Foreign aid shouldn't be seen as a controversial topic, but it tends to be. No one agrees that just throwing money at a problem makes it better, so why do we take this approach with countries? There have been many failures when it comes to foreign aid, and people use that as an excuse to argue for the end of foreign aid. As William Easterly points out, the reason that foreign aid fails is because the countries that fail don't have good existing policies in place to help allocate the aid that they receive. Most countries that get the aid are failures, but Easterly comments that they aren't called failures because the integrity of the foreign aid program would be compromised if the public knew how much foreign aid is unaccounted for. Governments and NGO's need to be more selective in giving aid in order to create a system where countries will be rewarded for their dedication to progress. Selectivity may seem cruel, but countries begging for money is even crueler because it debases their people. As this picture from Humans of New York points out, it's horrible to demote a whole country to their aid status because what they need is some faith and investment. Aid doesn't always work, and there needs to be something more than a one size fits all policy, but there's hope for every country with the right amount of legislative change.
Thursday, November 13, 2014
Wednesday, November 5, 2014
The Banker's New Clothes
The Banker’s New Clothes does something kind of incredible.
It manages to explain banking in plain English, with examples that anyone can
understand. While the Great Recession seems likes something that can be
explained rather easily, the aftereffects and actions we must take to prevent
the next meltdown might not seem so people friendly. Even better Admati and
Hellwig are able to cut through the financial jargon and rhetoric in order to
show people why Wall Street isn’t working, and why we aren’t taking the
necessary steps to fix it. The Banker’s New Clothes starts with a quote from
former French President Nicolas Sarkozy criticizing banks for taking the risks
that led to the financial meltdown. If Sarkozy felt so strongly about this, one
could infer that France then took the incentive to crack down on banks and
their risky lending behaviors. Admati and Hellwig are quick to point out their hypocrisy;
because French banks have been a major focus of concern in the European crisis since
of they have very little equity and a lot of short-term funding. This was one
of the reasons why Dexia, a French-Belgian bank, had to be bailed out twice in
4 years; their equity was less than 2% of their assets after the first bailout
which was depleted after September 2011, and was then unable to deal with the
Greek Crisis in October leading to the second bailout. Admati and Hellwig become very critical of
these situations because they know that it could’ve been prevented. Banks
continue to argue that any regulation is “expensive” and would diminish their
growth. Admati and Hellwig see this a bugbear saying, ““When bankers complain
that banking regulation is expensive, they typically do not take into account
the costs of their harming the rest of the financial system and the overall
economy with the risks that they take. Public policy, however, must consider
all the costs and not simply those to the bankers” Admati and Hellwig see this
and the new “regulations” as the apt named Bankers New Clothes, which stems
from the story The Emperor’s New Clothes. This is what Admati and Hellwig say
has been happening in the banking world, the new so-called regulations are
leaving banking naked, but no one is courageous enough to say anything. Admati
and Hellwig propose to break up big banks, because they reach a point where
they’re unmanageable and inefficient since they’re more subject to governance
and control problems. Retail banking in Germany, deposits and small-business
lending, is dominated by banks that are active only locally, in particular
savings banks in public ownership so they weren’t hit as hard during the
crisis. It was only the public banks that suffered and became a liability in
the economy.
Part of the reason this book is so successful is because it
takes banking examples and uses the example of a woman named Kate to explain
them. For example, if Kate buys a $300,000 house and her down payment or initial equity
is $30,000, a subsequent drop of 10 percent or more in the value of the house
will wipe out her entire equity and leave her underwater. By contrast, if Kate
invests $60,000 as a down payment, she will lose her entire equity only if the
price declines in value by 20 percent or more; otherwise she will continue to
have equity in the house. A bank usually only has about 5% equity so any drop
in the value of assets really endangers the bank’s solvency. What bankers don’t like about capital
regulation, though, is that it’s “expensive” the manner I quoted before. These
liquid assets don’t acquire interest, so the banks see it as a loss, but in
reality it would incentivize investment because the risk that would usually be
on the creditors and taxpayers would now be on the bank. This book’s views
might be seen as rather controversial, especially to bankers, but I think that
their controversy will lead to a more open discussion on compromise that will
incentivize people to learn more about the economy and stop their fear of confronting Wall Street.
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)